Unregulated AI Will Worsen Inequality, Warns Nobel-Winning Economist Joseph Stiglitz

A Nobel laureate in economics explains how artificial intelligence will affect inequality—and how solutions such as a shorter work week might mitigate its negative effects

Illustration of Joseph Stiglitz.

Shideh Ghandeharizadeh

For the first time since the 1960s, Hollywood writers and actors were on strike concurrently this past summer. One of the joint movement's motivating factors was generative artificial intelligence—the term for programs that produce humanlike text, images, audio and video more quickly and cheaply than artists can. The strikers feared studios' use of generative AI tools would replace or devalue human labor. This is a reasonable worry: one report suggests that thousands of jobs have already been lost to AI, and another estimates that hundreds of millions could eventually be automated. Left unchecked, this labor disruption could further concentrate wealth in the hands of companies and leave workers with less power than ever.

“Unfettered capitalism, unfettered innovation, does not lead to the general well-being of our society,” says Joseph E. Stiglitz, a winner of the 2001 Nobel Prize in economics, a professor at Columbia University, and chief economist at the Roosevelt Institute, a think tank based in New York City. “That's one of the results that I've shown very strongly. One can't just leave it to the market.” Striking workers could serve as one restriction on job automation. Government regulation also could limit AI's disruptive ability. Stiglitz, who has studied the science of inequality—and how we can reduce it—spoke with Scientific American about how AI will affect the U.S. economy and what should be done to prevent it from increasing economic inequality.

[An edited transcript of the interview follows.]


On supporting science journalism

If you're enjoying this article, consider supporting our award-winning journalism by subscribing. By purchasing a subscription you are helping to ensure the future of impactful stories about the discoveries and ideas shaping our world today.


Generative AI is already disrupting the job market. Copywriters have been laid off in favor of text-generating programs such as ChatGPT. IBM has said it will pause hiring on thousands of roles that could be done by AI. Do you see this trend continuing?

Yes, I do. But we don't know the extent to which it will happen. I think it will replace people in more routine jobs—you mentioned copywriting, copyediting. Where there are a set of rules, it can read and see whether those rules are followed. It may not have as good an eye for the exceptions, and so I think there's going to be a lot of AI-human interfacing: people will use AI as a productivity-enhancing tool.

Somebody trained ChatGPT on my data, and I tested it to see how well it did in answering questions from a journalist. I made up the questions, and I reviewed the answers. I thought on half the questions it did perfectly reasonably—and on three it was totally wrong. So I think my view is that it's not going to be unleashed without a lot of human interaction. You're going to have to check it—not only the quality of the answer but also the bias and whether it's gone down a rabbit hole and produced made-up references.

What about the possibility of AI creating jobs? Would that be enough to make up for some of the jobs that will disappear?

No, I don't think so. I think it's going to create a demand for different skills. AI is very much like a black box. By that, I mean even the people who create it don't understand exactly how it's functioning. So at least some people have speculated that managing an AI may require more linguistic humanities skills than mathematical skills. And it may create a change in the kinds of skills that are valuable in the labor market. I see it as, at least in many areas, increasing productivity enough that the demand for labor in those areas will go down. There will be jobs created, but my judgment is that there will be more jobs lost.

Could we end up in a situation where human-created work is a premium product, the way buyers might be willing to pay more for hand-woven sweaters than for machine-made ones?

Yes, there's a widespread sense that there's a kind of blandness to ChatGPT-generated material. There's always going to be a demand for creativity. I think the areas where it's going to replace us are very much the areas where, now, we don't put a lot of weight on who has written it—you know, it's a newsletter or something that, if it had been generated by a machine, we don't care.

As someone who studies inequality extensively, how do you see these changes in the job market contributing to inequality?

I'm very worried. In a way, robots have replaced routine physical work. And AI now is replacing routine white-collar work—or not replacing it but reducing the demand. So jobs that were routinely white collar, I think, will be at risk. And there are enough of those that it would have a macroeconomic effect on the level of inequality. It could amplify the sense of disillusionment.

Now, that poses an advantage and a disadvantage. It may mean that large fractions of the world, of the U.S., will face this inequality. On the other hand, if we get our macroeconomic policy right and create jobs, the jobs will be created everywhere. People won't have to move in the way they do right now, when the jobs that are created are in urban coastal cities, and the jobs that are lost are in the Midwest, the South, industrial towns. So some of the place-based inequality, which has played such a role in the divided U.S., may not be as bad.

And do you see any potential solutions to this issue of reduced demand for white-collar work?

Sure, two things: We increase aggregate demand to keep the economy closer to full employment, and we have active labor-market policies to train or retrain people for the new jobs created by AI. It may be that if we have good, distributed policies, people may say, “Well, our standard of living is sufficiently high—I don't need that many material goods.” They'll accept more leisure; we might move to a 30-hour week. In effect, our measured GDP [gross domestic product] would not be as high as it would be if we had a 35- to 40-hour week. But our objective is not measured GDP; our objective is well-being. It could well be that we decide to move to an equilibrium with overall shorter working weeks and more leisure. And that may be one way we accommodate this increased productivity and increased innovation.

How can we incentivize companies to shorten the workweek and accept reductions in overall profitability?

We may have to use government regulation because of the weakness of the bargaining power of workers—especially in the U.S. We passed the “hours and wages bill” [the Fair Labor Standards Act of 1938] in the Great Depression, which capped the workweek at 40 hours. That was a long time ago, and now we're in a new world. It may be the appropriate thing is to set it at 30 or 35 hours with a lot of flexibility, so if companies want to have the workers work more than that, then they pay them overtime.

What we must recognize is that we created a system where workers don't have much bargaining power. In that kind of world AI may be an ally of the employer and weaken workers' bargaining power even more, which could increase inequality even more. There is a role for government to try to steer innovation in ways that are more productivity-increasing and job-creating, not job-destroying.

Overall, do you feel optimistic or pessimistic about the situation with AI in the workplace?

I guess overall I feel pessimistic with respect to the issue of inequality. With the right policies, we could have higher productivity and less inequality, and everybody would be better off. But you might say that the political economy, the way that our politics have been working, has not been going in that direction.

So at one end I'm hopeful that if we did the right thing, AI would be great. But the question is: Will we be doing the right thing in our policy space? That's much more problematic.

Sophie Bushwick is tech editor at Scientific American. She runs the daily technology news coverage for the website, writes about everything from artificial intelligence to jumping robots for both digital and print publication, records YouTube and TikTok videos and hosts the podcast Tech, Quickly. Bushwick also makes frequent appearances on radio shows such as Science Friday and television networks, including CBS, MSNBC and National Geographic. She has more than a decade of experience as a science journalist based in New York City and previously worked at outlets such as Popular Science,Discover and Gizmodo. Follow Bushwick on X (formerly Twitter) @sophiebushwick

More by Sophie Bushwick
Scientific American Magazine Vol 329 Issue 5This article was originally published with the title “Will AI Worsen Inequality?” in Scientific American Magazine Vol. 329 No. 5 (), p. 83
doi:10.1038/scientificamerican1223-83